Of all the warning signs about the terrible state of our
Universities, the suicide last year of Stefan Grimm, Professor of toxicology at Imperial
College, was the most desperate. Like any unnecessary death – and
certainly the tragedy of suicide - we are left asking What if? Not only the
What ifs of the professor’s work – the ideas he was working on, the ideas he
would have gone on to develop had he lived – but also the “What ifs” of the
fallout from his death: the damage to those who were implicated in it, the
effect on friends and colleagues, the negative publicity, let alone the effects
on those who loved him. What if organisational circumstances and institutional
politics weighed more in his favour? Grimm, despite being well-published, had
been deemed by his departmental management to not have brought in enough money:
by the laws of toxic managerialism, he had to go. But his death touched a great
many as they pondered the kind of madness we have arrived at. Viewed through
the distorted mirror of academic metrics, his death had “impact”. But it was a death: the end of a set of possibilities for what might have been.
Whilst we are touched by the tragedy of suicide as if watching a university soap opera,
the risk is to lose sight of exactly what is lost. What is lost with the death of someone like Grimm is
contingency: it is the snuffing-out of possibilities and as-yet unrecognised
ideas. Contingencies in the University are not only at risk from tragic events
like Stefan Grimm. They are systematically being eroded by performance metrics like
the REF, and now the TEF will have a similar disastrous effect. Whilst
contingency is at the heart of what Universities do, our current measures for
the effectiveness of the university sector cannot see it. I want to suggest
some ways of addressing this.
First of all, let’s consider how the REF removes
contingencies in the system. Of all the possible brilliant ideas for research,
only a few are likely to achieve impact and success, immediately rewarding the
investment in them. There is no way of telling which of the many ideas, plans,
individual academics, and so on, are likely to 'pay out' a successful return.
This is partly because there is no single idea, plan or individual whose merit
can be individually measured: success depends on the intellectual
climate, market conditions, history, existing research trajectories and social
networks. An individual measure of the likelihood of success - like publication
- is on its own a poor indicator, particularly as it acquires a reputation as
an indicator by which funding decisions are made.
Contingencies can be removed if we fail to see them. The
easiest way of not seeing contingency is to see no differences between
contingencies. This is to “analogise” contingency: to see that contingency x is
the same as y – effectively to see x or y as ‘superfluous’ or ‘redundant’.
Academic judgements of quality are in a large part identifications of analogies
of arguments and results. Another way of removing contingency is to eliminate
it because despite any original academic difference it presents, this
difference is seen either not to fit the particular reductionist disciplinary
criteria of a reviewer (“this is not about education, but economics…”), or to
be published in an insufficiently “high-ranking” journal. Judgements of quality
are judgements about redundancy of ideas based on written communications – and
redundant work can lead to redundant academics. As with peer review, analogies,
redundancies and contingencies exist as relationships between reviewers and the
things they review: there is no objective assessment, and there is no way of
assessing what analogies or differences a reviewer is predisposed to identify
in the first place. We understand this so poorly, and so little of
it is available for inspection. Its consequence in systematically removing
contingency from the system is dire.
Of course, it might be argued that removing some contingency
may sometimes be necessary, as a gardener might deadhead roses. But the
gardener does this not to reduce contingency in the long-run, but to maintain
multiple contingencies of stems, leaves and flowers. In the university
contingencies of practices, ideas, relationships and conversations are
necessary so that the institutional conditions are maintained to make maximum benefit
of the most appropriate ideas in the appropriate conditions. The British
Library or the Bodleian make a point of preserving contingencies by keeping a
copy of everything that is published: one would hope this would reflect a
similar culture in our universities which traditionally has always exhibited
many contingencies – it is the principal distinction between higher learning
and schooling.
The consequence of removing contingency is increasing
rigidity in the system, producing an education system which knows only a few
ways to respond to a fast-changing world. There are contingencies not only
among the possible ideas which might be thought, researched and developed
within the university; there are contingencies in ways of teaching, the
activities that are conducted by learners and teachers; the ways learners are
assessed; the conditions within which teachers and learners can meet and talk;
the technological variety for maintaining conversations, and the broader means
by which conversations are sustained.
Contingencies are not only under attack from research
budgets and assessment exercises. Government-inspired regulatory mechanisms are
the handmaiden of marketing campaigns. Good scores = good marketing = good
recruitment. But marketization produces its own pressures on the removal of
contingencies: closure of whole departments like philosophy, concentration on popular subjects like IT or Business, not to
mention the blinkered drive for ‘STEM’ as universities confuse science with
textbook-performances of useless sums. Alongside these pressures to remove
academic contingencies is an attempt to remove contingencies in academic and
pedagogical practice. The contingencies of university life are deeply
interconnected: the contingencies of pedagogy have been eroded by learning
outcomes, disciplinary reductionism, competency frameworks, and the various
indicators of ‘academic quality’. The recently-announced Teaching Excellence
Framework amounts to a renewed assault on the contingencies in the classroom.
An institution not recognised by the REF might nevertheless claim success in
teaching, but if this success can only be defined through recognition in
metrics, the TEF will reduce diversity of teaching practice, drive out experimentation,
and bureaucratise the process to produce outcomes that fit locally-defined
criteria aimed at gaming success with national inspection. One university I
know, its ear close to Westminster, announced its new strategy of being
“Teaching Intensive, Research Informed” in a bid to find favour with the new
regulatory climate: in a stroke, fearless pedagogical experimentation,
diversity, freedom and flexibility become subsumed into ‘intensive teaching’
driven by metrics on teacher performance and ‘student satisfaction’,
accompanied with implicit threats of redundancy, with the only real desire that
students stay on the course and continue to pay their fees.
The REF and the TEF are two sides of the same coin.
Following a ‘business-oriented’ logic, their effect is to reduce contingencies
in the University. But universities are unlike businesses precisely in their
relationship to contingency: if universities lose contingencies they cease to
be universities but (at best) schools. What should we do?
We can and should be measuring the contingencies of the
higher education system, and allocating funding according to a much broader
conception of a higher education ecology. Ironically, bibliometric approaches
partly used in the REF take us half-way there. Typically, bibliometrics measure
the ‘mutual information’ in discourses: those topics which recur across
different contexts – those areas where contingency is lost. Contingencies sit
in the background to this ‘mutual information’. In effect they operate as the
“constraints” which produce repeated patterns of practice, which if probed, can
unlock new research potential. New discoveries are made when we see things that
we once thought were analogous to be fundamentally different, and then start to
explore these differences.
The contingencies of pedagogy are also measurable: if we
took all the learning outcomes, all the assignment briefs, subject handbooks and
so on in the country, we would see high degree of ‘mutual information’ (of
course, our ‘quality regime’ depends on this!). What are the constraints which
produce this? (apart from the QAA or its successor) Why is there not more
diversity? How can funding be targeted to generate more variety in pedagogic
practice? If we are to get the balance between contingency and coherence in our
Universities, a much broader, but also more analytical approach is required.
Most importantly it has to sit outside marketization – at the level of
government: marketization is one of many constraints which currently serve to
reduce contingency. At the moment, the REF and the TEF both feed marketisation
producing a positive feedback loop. Higher Education is out-of-control. The monitoring
of levels of contingency would show where things are going wrong. We might hope
that it also helps us to steer our higher education system to maximise, not
reduce, its contingency. At the very least, we should aim to produce the
conditions within which Stefan Grimm would still be alive thinking new
ideas.
No comments:
Post a Comment